Reassessing the fall in US public debt after World War II (2024)

Does a high level of national debt impose a burden on future generations who must pay it off? Inrecent years, economists such as Blanchard (2019) and Furman and Summers (2020) have suggested that the answer may be no, because r < g: the real interest rate on debt is usually below the growth rate of the economy. Under that condition, the government can roll over the debt and accumulate interest without raising taxes, and the debt/GDP ratio will fall over time. This idea has decreased concern about the high current level of US debt.

Thinking on this issue has been influenced by a salient historical experience: the decline in the US debt/GDP ratio after WWII. Paying for the war increased this ratio from 42% in fiscal year 1941 to 106% in 1946, but then it started to fall and reached a trough of 23% in fiscal year 1974. As Elmendorf and Mankiw (1999) report, “an important factor behind the dramatic drop between 1945 and 1975 is that the growth rate of GDP exceeded the interest rate on government debt for most of that period.” Krugman (2012) says that the “debt from World War II was never repaid and just became increasingly irrelevant as the US economy grew.” This interpretation of history lends credence to the idea that a high level of debt should not cause great concern.

However, other researchers have suggested reasons to question this interpretation. First, as discussed by authors such as Hall and Sargent (2011) and Eichengreen and Esteves (2022a, 2022b), the US actually paid off part of the WWII debt by running primary surpluses—by levying taxes in excess of current government spending—over much of the period when the debt/GDP ratio was falling. Second, as discussed by authors such as Reinhart and Sbrancia (2015), interest rates were held down relative to economic growth through policies that are not likely to be feasible and/or desirable in the future. These policies included episodes of financial repression, most clearly the Fed’s pegging of interest rates at low levels from 1942 to 1951, which was aimed at decreasing the cost of the war. In addition, ex-post real interest rates were reduced by unexpected rises in inflation in the aftermath of the war and later in the 1960s and 1970s. Because of these factors, the post-war experience does not necessarily suggest that the US economy naturally grows out of debt.

In a recent paper (Acalin and Ball 2023), we seek to quantify the different factors driving the debt/GDP ratio since its 1946 peak. To do so, we construct a term structure of inflation expectations from surveys of short- and long-term expectations, which allows us to estimate the effects of surprise inflation on the real returns on debt. We also estimate the effects of the pre-1952 interest rate peg by comparing the pegged rates on debt of various maturities to market rates during the post-peg period of 1952-1960. Finally, we measure the fractions of outstanding debt in a given year that were issued in each earlier year—the ‘reverse maturity structure’ of the debt—which we do using granular data on Treasury securities produced by Hall et al. (2018) before 1960 and by the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) thereafter. The reverse maturity structure matters because the debt in a given year may include some securities issued during the pre-1952 peg and some issued later, and because inflation expectations differed at the various times securities were issued.

Counterfactual debt paths

We summarise our findings by presenting the paths of the debt/GDP ratio in three counterfactual scenarios. In one, the ‘primary balance scenario’, we set the primary surplus to zero in all years (but leave interest rates unchanged at their historical levels). In another, the ‘adjusted interest rate scenario’, we eliminate the effects on rates of both surprise inflation and the Fed’s peg before 1952 (but leave primary surpluses at their historical levels). Finally, in a ‘combined scenario’ we assume primary balance and also adjust interest rates. The combined scenario shows how much the debt/GDP ratio was reduced by growth rates in excess of undistorted real interest rates—the decrease that reflects the economy’s natural tendency to grow out of debt.

Figure 1 presents the actual and counterfactual paths of debt/GDP, which all start with the ratio at its actual level of 106% in 1946. In interpreting these results, we divide the period since 1946 into two parts: 1946-1974, when the actual debt/GDP ratio declined to its trough of 23%; and 1975-2022, when the ratio rose to 97%. For each counterfactual, Table 1 reports the total changes in debt/GDP over the two periods.

Over 1946-1974, the actual debt/GDP ratio declined steeply. Our counterfactual ratios also decline, but more slowly. As a result, while the actual debt/GDP ratio reached 23% in 1974, the counterfactual ratios in 1974 are substantially higher: 40% in the primary balance scenario, 51% in the adjusted rate scenario, and 74% in the combined scenario. Over the three decades after WWII, the natural erosion of debt from economic growth, as captured by the combined scenario, was considerably smaller than is often suggested.

Figure 1 Debt/GDP paths: Counterfactual scenarios

Reassessing the fall in US public debt after World War II (1)
Note: The lines represent the path of the debt-GDP ratio in actual history and our different counterfactual scenarios. Source: Authors’ calculations

To appreciate these results, recall that the actual debt/GDP ratio fell by 83 percentage points from 1946 to 1974 (from 106% to 23%). In the combined scenario, the ratio falls by only 32 points (from 106% to 74%). Therefore, of the actual 83-point fall, 51 points are explained by the combination of primary surpluses and interest rate distortions. By comparing the different counterfactuals, we can divide these 51 points into 17 points explained by primary surpluses alone, 28 points explained by interest rate distortions alone, and six points from the interaction of the two factors. The interaction arises because adjusting the primary balance raises the level of debt, and higher debt magnifies the effects of adjusting interest rates.

When we extend our counterfactuals to 2022, they yield even more negative findings about growing out of debt. In the combined counterfactual with primary balance and undistorted real interest rates, the debt/GDP ratio falls from its 1974 level of 74% to 70% in 1979, but then starts to rise. The rise in the combined counterfactual ratio reflects the fact that the economy's growth rate has averaged less than the undistorted real interest rate on debt since 1980. In 2022, the counterfactual debt/GDP ratio is 84%: the earlier decline in the ratio is partially reversed. (The actual debt/GDP ratio has risen from its trough of 23% to 97%, mostly because of a shift from primary surpluses before 1974 to large primary deficits in recent decades.)

Table 1 Debt/GDP ratio: Actual and counterfactuals (%)

Notes: The table shows the values of the debt/GDP ratio in actual history and our counterfactuals in 1946, 1974, and 2022.
Source: OMB, authors’ calculations

Looking forward

All in all, our findings cast doubt on the common narrative that the US ‘grew its way’ out of its WWII debt. Over the 76 years from 1946 to 2022, economic growth without primary surpluses or interest-rate distortions would have reduced the debt/GDP ratio by only 22 percentage points, from 106% to 84%. History suggests that we should not count on a major contribution from economic growth to resolving the problem of a high debt level.

What then are the prospects for reducing the debt/GDP ratio from its current level of 97%? It is unlikely that the interest-rate distortions that reduced the ratio after WWII will occur again. Presumably, US policymakers are not considering the kind of interest-rate peg that was imposed during WWII (which required price controls to contain the inflationary effects). And despite the recent surge in inflation, the Federal Reserve appears committed to pushing inflation back down and keeping it low, which would preclude debt erosion through surprise inflation. Additionally, any inflation surprises that occur will have smaller effects than they did in the past because the average maturity of the debt is shorter (Aizenman and Marion 2009, 2011 and Hilscher at al. 2014, 2021).

The upshot is that reducing the debt/GDP ratio will probably require primary budget surpluses. Yet surpluses also appear unlikely: under current policy, the Congressional Budget Office predicts large primary deficits over the next three decades. Absent a major shift toward fiscal consolidation, these deficits are likely to push the debt/GDP ratio to higher and potentially unsustainable levels.

Authors' note:The views herein are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the IMF, its Executive Board or its management

References

Acalin, J and L Ball (2023), “Did the US really grow its way out of its WWII debt?”, NBER Working Paper No. w31577.

Aizenman, J and N Marion (2009), “Using inflation to erode the US public debt”, VoxEU.org, 18 December.

Aizenman, J and N Marion (2011), “Using Inflation to Erode the U.S. Public Debt”, Journal of Macroeconomics 33: 524–541.

Blanchard, O (2019), “Public Debt and Low Interest Rates”, American Economic Review 109: 1197–12.

Eichengreen, B and R Esteves (2022a), “Up and Away? Inflation and Debt Consolidation in Historical Perspective”, Oxford Open Economics 1.

Eichengreen, B and R Esteves (2022b), “Up and away: Inflation and debt consolidation in historical perspective”, VoxEU.org, 15 November.

Elmendorf, D W and N G Mankiw (1999), “Government Debt”, Handbook of Macroeconomics 1: 1615–1669.

Furman, J and L Summers (2020), “A Reconsideration of Fiscal Policy in the Era of Low Interest Rates”, unpublished manuscript, Brookings Institution.

Hall, G, J Payne and T J Sargent (2018), “US Federal Debt 1776-1960: Quantities and Prices”, Working Paper 18-25, New York University, Leonard N. Stern School of Business, Department of Economics.

Hall, G J and T J Sargent (2011), “Interest Rate Risk and Other Determinants of Post-WWII US Government Debt/GDP Dynamics”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 3: 192–214.

Hilscher, J, A Raviv, and R Reis (2014), “Will the US inflate away its public debt?”, VoxEU.org, 7 August.

Hilscher, J, A Raviv and R Reis (2021), “Inflating Away the Public Debt? An Empirical Assessment”, The Review of Financial Studies 35(3): 1553-1595.

Krugman, P (2012), “Nobody Understands Debt”, The New York Times, 1 January.

Reinhart, C M and M B Sbrancia (2015), “The Liquidation of Government Debt”, Economic Policy 30: 291–333.

Reassessing the fall in US public debt after World War II (2024)

FAQs

How did the US reduce debt after WWII? ›

Fiscal and Economic Policies Helped to Reduce Debt-to-GDP After 1946. A recent working paper from researchers Julien Acalin and Laurence Ball pointed to two key factors – in addition to economic expansion – that fueled the fall in the debt-to-GDP ratio after 1946: primary surpluses and interest rate distortions.

How did the increase in U.S. debt during World War II compare to the debt level in 1940? ›

The buildup to World War II brought the debt up another order of magnitude from $51 billion in 1940 to $260 billion following the war. After this period, the debt's growth closely matched the rate of inflation until the 1980s, when it again began to increase rapidly.

How did WWI affect the national debt in the United States? ›

The Government also raised money by selling "Liberty Bonds." Americans bought the bonds to help the Government pay for the war. Later, they were paid back the value of their bonds plus interest. By the end of the war, the Government's debt was more than $25 billion.

Did America go into debt after the Civil war? ›

By the end of the war in 1865, Government debt had exploded, reaching $2.6 billion. That was more than 40 times what it was only five years earlier at $65 million. 1860 - The U.S. Government debt was $64.8 million.

Did the United States want to help to relieve the debt of allies after World War 1? ›

Meanwhile, a second wartime financial issue was causing tension among the former co-belligerents. While the United States had little interest in collecting reparations from Germany, it was determined to secure repayment of the more than $10 billion it had loaned to the Allies over the course of the war.

How does the US reduce its debt? ›

Most include a combination of deep spending cuts and tax increases to bend the debt curve. Cutting spending. Most comprehensive proposals to rein in the debt include major cuts to spending on entitlement programs and defense.

Who is the US debt owed to? ›

The public includes foreign investors and foreign governments. These two groups account for 30 percent of the debt. Individual investors and banks represent 15 percent of the debt. The Federal Reserve is holding 12 percent of the treasuries issued.

Has the US ever been debt free? ›

However, President Andrew Jackson shrank that debt to zero in 1835. It was the only time in U.S. history when the country was free of debt.

What would happen if the US paid off its debt? ›

Answer and Explanation:

If the U.S. was to pay off their debt ultimately, there is not much that would happen. Paying off the debt implies that the government will now focus on using the revenue collected primarily from taxes to fund its activities.

How did ww1 affect the US financially? ›

When the war began, the U.S. economy was in recession. But a 44-month economic boom ensued from 1914 to 1918, first as Europeans began purchasing U.S. goods for the war and later as the United States itself joined the battle.

What was the effect of war debt? ›

This borrowing has raised the U.S. budget deficit, increased the national debt and had other macroeconomic effects, such as raising consumer interest rates. Unless the U.S. immediately repays the money borrowed for war, there will also be future interest payments.

What is the oldest debt the US has? ›

The U.S. has carried debt since its inception. Debts incurred during the American Revolutionary War amounted to over $75 million by January 1, 1791. Over the next 45 years, the debt continued to grow until 1835 when it notably shrank due to the sale of federally-owned lands and cuts to the federal budget.

Has the US paid off WWII debt? ›

First, as discussed by authors such as Hall and Sargent (2011) and Eichengreen and Esteves (2022a, 2022b), the US actually paid off part of the WWII debt by running primary surpluses—by levying taxes in excess of current government spending—over much of the period when the debt/GDP ratio was falling.

Which country has the highest debt? ›

Japan has the highest percentage of national debt in the world at 259.43% of its annual GDP.

What country has the least debt? ›

Countries with the Lowest National Debt
  • Brunei. 3.2%
  • Afghanistan. 7.8%
  • Kuwait. 11.5%
  • Democratic Republic of Congo. 15.2%
  • Eswatini. 15.5%
  • Palestine. 16.4%
  • Russia. 17.8%

How did ww2 save the U.S. economy? ›

American factories were retooled to produce goods to support the war effort and almost overnight the unemployment rate dropped to around 10%. As more men were sent away to fight, women were hired to take over their positions on the assembly lines.

How did the U.S. pay off the Revolutionary war debt? ›

When the war ended, the United States had spent $37 million at the national level and $114 million at the state level. The United States finally solved its debt problems in the 1790s when Alexander Hamilton founded the First Bank of the United States in order to pay off war debts and establish good national credit.

What led to economic recovery after WWII? ›

While these investments undoubtedly aided in economic recovery after the war, most historians now conclude that the most important American long-term influences were removing trade tariffs, the "Americanization" of business structures, and the new wave of private investment that followed.

Why was the U.S. so successful after ww2? ›

The economy thrived after World War II in large part because America made it easier for people who had been previously shut out of economic opportunity — women, minority groups, immigrants — to enter the work force and climb the economic ladder, to make better use of their talents and potential.

Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Frankie Dare

Last Updated:

Views: 5971

Rating: 4.2 / 5 (53 voted)

Reviews: 84% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Frankie Dare

Birthday: 2000-01-27

Address: Suite 313 45115 Caridad Freeway, Port Barabaraville, MS 66713

Phone: +3769542039359

Job: Sales Manager

Hobby: Baton twirling, Stand-up comedy, Leather crafting, Rugby, tabletop games, Jigsaw puzzles, Air sports

Introduction: My name is Frankie Dare, I am a funny, beautiful, proud, fair, pleasant, cheerful, enthusiastic person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.